Rent-seeking: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
AnomieBOT (talk | contribs)
{{Competition law}}
 
(38 intermediate revisions by 25 users not shown)
Line 1:
{{Short description|AttemptGrowing toone's makeexisting moneywealth bywithout stiflingcreating competitionnew through lobbying, intimidation or corruptionwealth}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=November 2018}}
{{State monopoly capitalism}}
{{Capitalism sidebar}}
{{Competition law}}
'''Rent-seeking''' is the act of growing one's existing [[wealth]] by manipulating the social or political environment without creating new wealth.<ref>
'''Rent-seeking''' is the act of growing one's existing wealth by manipulating the social or political environment without creating new wealth.<ref>
Compare: {{oed | rent-seeking}} - "'''rent-seeking''' n. ''Economics''[:] the fact or process of seeking to gain larger profits by manipulating public policy or economic conditions, esp. by means of securing beneficial subsidies or tariffs, making a product artificially scarce, etc. [...]"
</ref>
Rent-seeking activities have negative effects on the rest of society. They result in reduced [[economic efficiency]] through [[allocation of resources|misallocation of resources]], stifled [[Competition (economics)|competition]], reduced [[wealth creation]], lost [[government revenue]], heightened [[income inequality]],<ref>{{cite web |url= https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2001/wp0115.pdf |title= Rent-seeking and Endogenous Income Inequality |author= IMF |access-date= 30 April 2014}}</ref><ref name="Deaton2023"/> risk of growing political[[corruption]] briberyand [[cronyism]], decreased [[public trust]] in institutions and potential national decline.
 
Attempts atSuccessful [[regulatory capture|capture of regulatory agencies]] (if any) to gain a [[coercive monopoly]] can result in advantages for rent-seekers in a [[market (economics)|market]] while imposing disadvantages on their uncorrupt competitors. This is one of many possible forms of rent-seeking behavior.
 
==Description==
Line 14:
The term rent, in the narrow sense of [[economic rent]], was coined by the British 19th-century economist [[David Ricardo]],<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/RentSeeking.html |title=Rent Seeking |last= Henderson|first= David R. |author-link=David R. Henderson |publisher=[[Econlib.org]]}}<!-- This is an original essay by Henderson, not available via other sources. --></ref> but rent-seeking only became the subject of durable interest among economists and political scientists more than a century later after the publication of two influential papers on the topic by [[Gordon Tullock]] in 1967,<ref>{{cite journal |last=Tullock |first=Gordon |year=1967 |title=The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft |journal=Western Economic Journal |volume=5 |pages=224–232}}</ref> and [[Anne Krueger]]<ref name=Krueger1974>{{cite journal |last=Krueger |first=Anne |year=1974 |title=The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society |journal=American Economic Review |volume=64 |issue=3 |pages=291–303 |jstor=1808883}}</ref> in 1974. The word "rent" does not refer specifically to payment on a lease but rather to [[Adam Smith]]'s division of incomes into [[Profit (economics)|profit]], wage, and economic rent. The origin of the term refers to gaining control of [[land (economics)|land]] or other natural resources. {{Citation needed|date=November 2022}}
 
[[Georgist]] economic theory describes rent-seeking in terms of land rent, where the value of land largely comes from the natural resources native to the land, as well as collectively paid for services, for example: [[State school]]sschools, law enforcement, fire prevention and, mitigation services, etc. Rent seeking to the Georgist does not include those persons that may have invested substantial capital improvements to a piece of land, but rather those that perform in their role as mere titleholder. This is the dividing line between a rent-seeker and a [[property developer]], which need not be the same person.{{Citation needed|date=November 2022}}
 
''Rent-seeking'' is an attempt to obtain economic rent (i.e., the portion of income paid to a [[factor of production]] in excess of what is needed to keep it employed in its current use) by manipulating the social or political environment in which economic activities occur, rather than by [[value added|creating new wealth]]. Rent-seeking implies extraction of uncompensated value from others without making any contribution to [[productivity (economics)|productivity]]. Because the nature of rent-seeking implies a fixed cost payment, only wealthy participants engage in these activities as a means of protecting their wealth from expropriation.<ref>{{cite book |last=Chakraborty |first=Shankha |year=2005 |title=Rent Seeking |journalseries=IMF Working Papers |volume=05 |publisher=International Monetary Fund |issue=43 |page=1 |doi=10.5089/9781451860627.001 |isbn=978-1-4518-6062-7 |s2cid=15557383 | issn=1018-5941}}</ref>
 
In many market-driven economies, much of the competition for rents is legal, regardless of any harm it may do to an economy.{{Citation needed|date=January 2022}} However, various rent-seeking behaviors are illegal, such as the forming of [[cartel]]s or the [[Bribery|bribing]] of politicians.
 
Rent-seeking is distinguished in theory from [[Profit (economics)|profit-seeking]], in which entities seek to extract value by engaging in mutually beneficial transactions.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://ingrimayne.saintjoe.edu/econ/government/RentSeeking.html |title=Rent Seeking |first=Robert|last= Schenk |work=CyberEconomics |access-date=11 February 2007 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060103062417/http://ingrimayne.saintjoe.edu/econ/government/RentSeeking.html |archive-date=3 January 2006}}</ref> Profit-seeking in this sense is the creation of wealth, while rent-seeking is "[[profiteering (business)|profiteering]]" by using social institutions, such as but not limited to the power of the state, to redistribute wealth among different groups without creating new wealth.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Conybeare |first=John A. C. |year=1982 |title=The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification |journal=[[World Politics]] |volume=35 |issue=1 |pages=25–42 |doi=10.2307/2010278 |jstor=2010278 |s2cid=154601921 }}</ref> In a practical context, income obtained through rent-seeking may contribute to [[Profit (accounting)|profits in the standard, accounting sense of the word]].{{Citation needed|date=September 2021}}
 
===Tullock paradox===
The Tullock paradox is the apparent [[paradox]], described by economist [[Gordon Tullock]], on the low costs of rent-seeking relative to the gains from rent-seeking.<ref name="tullock1980">{{cite book |last=Tullock |first=Gordon |year=1980 |chapter=Efficient rent-seeking |title=Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society |editor=Buchanan, J. |editor2=Tollison, R. |editor3=Tullock, G. |publisher=Texas A&M Press |place=College Station |pages=97–112 |isbn=0-89096-090-9}}</ref><ref name="connes">{{cite periodical |date=September 2003|title=Loss Aversion and the Tullock Paradox |last1=Connes |first1=Richard |last2=Hartley |first2=Roger |citeseerx=10.1.1.624.4082 |periodical=Discussion Papers in Economics |number=3/17 |url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/5159311 |via=ResearchGate}}</ref>
 
The paradox is that rent-seekers wanting political favors can bribe politicians at a cost much lower than the value of the favor to the rent-seeker. For instance, a rent seeker who hopes to gain a billion dollars from a particular political policy may need to bribe politicians with merely ten million dollars, which is about 1% of the gain to the rent-seeker. [[Luigi Zingales]] frames it by asking, "Why is there so little money in politics?" because a naïve model of political bribery and/or campaign spending should result in beneficiaries of government subsidies being willing to spend an amount up toapproaching the value of the profits derived from the subsidies themselves, when in fact only a small fraction of that is spent.<ref>{{cite book|first1=Luigi|last1=Zingales|title=A Capitalism for the People: Recapturing the Lost Genius of American Prosperity|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=USzXmw5CJ_MC|publisher=Basic Books|date=5 June 2012|isbn=978-0-465-02947-1|via=Google Books}}</ref>
 
====Possible explanations====
Line 38:
[[File:PapalPolitics2.JPG|thumb|''Antichristus'',<ref>{{cite book |url= https://books.google.com/books?id=NMQ_Ar84DCcC |title=Passional Christi und Antichristi |last1=Luther |first1=Martin |year=1521 }}</ref> a woodcut by [[Lucas Cranach the Elder]], of the pope using the temporal power to grant authority to a ruler contributing generously to the Catholic Church]]
 
The classic example of rent-seeking, according to [[Robert Shiller]], is that of a property owner who installs a chain across a river that flows through histheir land and then hires a collector to charge passing boats a fee to lower the chain. There is nothing productive about the chain or the collector, nor do passing boats get anything in return. The owner has made no improvements to the river and is not adding value in any way, directly or indirectly, except for himselfthemselves. All hethey isare doing is finding a way [[Parasitism|to obtain money]] from something that used to be free.<ref>{{cite web |last=Shiller |first=Robert |author-link=Robert Shiller |date=20 September 2013 |title=The Best, Brightest and Least Productive? |url=http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/the-rent-seeking-problem-in-contemporary-finance-by-robert-j--shiller |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211016052828/https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/the-rent-seeking-problem-in-contemporary-finance-by-robert-j--shiller-2013-09 |archive-date=October 16, 2021 |website=project-syndicate.org |publisher=[[Project Syndicate]]}}</ref>
 
An example of rent-seeking in a modern economy is spending money on lobbying for government subsidies in order to be given wealth that has already been created, or to impose regulations on competitors, in order to increase one's own market share.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Samples |first1=John |title=An Introduction to Rent Seeking |url= https://www.libertarianism.org/blog/introduction-rent-seeking |work=libertarianism.org |date=May 30, 2012 }}</ref> Another example of rent-seeking is the limiting of access to lucrative occupations, as by medieval [[guild]]s or modern state certifications and [[licensure]]s. According to some libertarian perspectives, [[taxi]] licensing is a textbook example of rent-seeking.<ref>{{cite book |last1=McTaggart |first1=Douglas |title=Economics |date=2012 |publisher= Pearson Higher Education |isbn=978-1-4425-5077-3 |page=224}}</ref> To the extent that the issuing of licenses constrains overall supply of taxi services (rather than ensuring competence or quality), forbidding competition from other [[vehicles for hire]] renders the (otherwise consensual) transaction of taxi service a forced transfer of part of the fee, from customers to taxi business proprietors.
 
The concept of rent-seeking would also apply to corruption of bureaucrats who solicit and extract "bribe" or "rent" for applying their legal but discretionary authority for awarding legitimate or illegitimate benefits to clients.<ref name="Chowdhury 2006">{{cite book |last=Chowdhury |first=Faizul Latif |year=2006 |title=Corrupt Bureaucracy and Privatization of Tax Enforcement in Bangladesh |publisher=Pathak Shamabesh, Dhaka |isbn=978-984-8120-62-0}}</ref> For example, taxpayers may bribe officials to lessen their tax burden.
Line 48:
Rent-seeking through government enterprise takes the form of seeking [[subsidies]] and avoiding [[tariffs]]. This seems like the actions of a firm looking for investment in [[productivity]] but in doing so creates an exclusionary effect for more productive firms.<ref>{{cite journal |first1=Liu |last1=Baohua |first2=Lin |last2=Yan |first3=Chan |last3=Kam.C |first4=Fung |last4=Hung-Gay |title=The dark side of rent-seeking: The impact of rent-seeking on earnings management |year=2018 |volume=91 |issue=1 |pages=94–107 |journal=Journal of Business Research |doi=10.1016/j.jbusres.2018.05.037 |s2cid=158315455 }}</ref>
 
Lotta Moberg presents an argument that export processing zones (EPZ) allow governments to choose exporting industries which receive tariffs allowing for rent seeking to take place. An example of this occurred in Latin America in the 1960s with [[Joaquín Balaguer]]'s response to pressure from the United States to open the Dominican Republic's export market. At the time, the United States was a massive trading partner for sugar while providing foreign aid and military support which allowed Balaguer's regime to take hold. Joaquín Balaguer used EPZ to allow for some markets to remain tariffed while appeasing the markets facing political pressures. This created a sub-optimal environment for exporters as they were able to invest in rent seeking activities ([[lobbying]]) to gain access to EPZ to gain [[tax]] and [[tariff]] exemptions.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Moberg |first=Lotta |title=Liberalizing rent-seeking: How export processing zones can save or sink an economy |year=2018 |volume=33 |issue=4 |pages=61–89 |journal=Journal of Private Enterprise |publisher=Association of Private Enterprise Education |location=Texas|issn=0890-913X |url-access=registration |url= http://journal.apee.org/index.php?title=2018_Journal_of_Private_Enterprise_Vol_33_No_4_Winter_parte4}}</ref>
 
In some cases, rent-seeking can provide a net positive for an economy. Shannon K. Mitchell's article "The Welfare Effects of Rent-Saving and Rent-Seeking" provides such an example through a model of rent-seeking when firms need to expand to obtain their exporting rents.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Shannon |first=Mitchell |year=1993 |title=The Welfare Effects of Rent-Saving and Rent-Seeking |journal=The Canadian Journal of Economics |publisher=Wiley on behalf of the Canadian Economics Association |volume=26 |issue=3 |pages=660–669 |doi=10.2307/135893 |jstor=135893}}</ref>
 
Economists such as [[Lord Turner of Ecchinswell|Lord Adair Turner]], the former chair of the British [[Financial Services Authority]], have argued that [[Financial innovation|innovation in the financial industry]] is often a form of rent-seeking.<ref>{{cite report |last=Turner |first=Adair |title= Securitisation, Shadow Banking and the Value of Financial Innovation |publisher=Johns Hopkins University |date=19 April 2012 |series=School of Advanced International Studies |issue=The Rostov Lecture on International Affairs |url= http://www.fsa.gov.uk/static/pubs/speeches/0419-at.pdf |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20121003063000/http://www.fsa.gov.uk/static/pubs/speeches/slides-0419-at.pdf|archive-date=3 October 2012 }}</ref><ref>{{cite speech |last=Turner |first=Adair |title=What do banks do, what should they do and what public policies are needed to ensure best results for the real economy? |website= FSA.gov.uk| date=17 March 2010 |page=27 |url= http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/speeches/at_17mar10.pdf |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20101007114307/http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/speeches/at_17mar10.pdf|archive-date=7 October 2010 }}[?]</ref>
 
==== International perspectives ====
Rent-seeking is not limited to any singular country or region. Rent-seeking manifests and impacts many different societies and economies.
 
The oil industry in Nigeria is heavily impacted by rent-seeking. Nigeria is a rich in oil reserves, but sees a large amount of its profits siphoned off by corrupt officials and individuals who are engaging in rent-seeking behavior, leading to a wide income gap between the wealthy and the poor, as well as widespread poverty and political instability.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Osaghae |first=Eghosa |title=Oil, Rent-Seeking and Democracy in Nigeria |journal=African Journal of Political Science and International Relations |volume=2 |issue=4 |year=2008 |pages=75–82}}</ref>
 
Another example of rent-seeking can be found in the banking sector in Iceland. Leading up to the 2008 financial crisis, the Icelandic banks engaged in rent-seeking behavior by inflating asset prices, engaging in speculative investments and giving out large bonuses to executives. This eventually led to the collapse of Iceland's banking system and national economic crisis.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Zoega |first=Gylfi |year=2012 |title=Iceland's Collapse |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |volume=26 |issue=2 |pages=25–46 |doi=10.1257/jep.26.2.25 }}</ref>
 
==Development of theory==
Line 67 ⟶ 60:
 
===Criticism===
In the 1980s, critiques of rent-seeking theory began to emerge, questioning the ambiguity of the concept of "wasted resources" and the reliability of the assumptions being made from it.<ref name="Samuels 1992 111–128">{{cite journalbook |chapter-url=https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-1-349-12377-3_6 |last= Samuels |first=W. J. |title=A Critique of Rent-seeking Theory |journal=Essays on the Economic Role of Government |chapter= A Critique of Rent-seeking Theory |year=1992 |volume=2 |pages=111–128 |doi=10.1007/978-1-349-12377-3_6|isbn= 978-1-349-12379-7 }}</ref> Samuels argues that [[productivity]] is defined by rent-seeking theorists as a strictly physical property but ignores the rights that surround and define the product. He further asserts that rent-seeking theorists ignore a fundamental principle of being economic actors: that we live in markets of [[scarcity|scarce resources]] and it's how we utiliseuse these resources which drives [[supply and demand]], and the notion of "wasted resources" rejects our preferences to allocate those resources.<ref name="Samuels 1992 111–128"/>
 
Writing in ''[[The Review of Austrian Economics]]'', [[Ernest C. Pasour]] says that there may be difficulties distinguishing between beneficial profit-seeking and detrimental rent-seeking.<ref>{{cite journal |url=https://www.mises.org/journals/rae/pdf/rae1_1_8.pdf |last=Pasour |first=E. C. |title=Rent Seeking: Some Conceptual Problems and Implications |journal=[[The Review of Austrian Economics]] |year=1987 |volume=1 |issue=1 |pages=123–143 |doi=10.1007/BF01539337 |s2cid=18809359 }}</ref>
 
In 2023, [[Angus Deaton]] wrote:
==Rent-seeking in the digital age==
With constantly evolving digital platforms and new business models, individuals or groups are always on the lookout to gain an unfair advantage over others using the government or other institutions.
 
<blockquote>In retrospect it is not so surprising that free markets, or at least free markets with a government that permits and encourages rent seeking by the rich, should produce not equality but an extractive elite that predates on the population at large. Utopian rhetoric about freedom has led to an unjust social dystopia, not for the first time. Free markets with rent seekers are not the same as ''competitive'' markets; indeed, they are often exactly the opposite.<ref name="Deaton2023">{{cite book |last=Deaton|first=Angus|author-link=Angus Deaton|date=2023 |title=Economics in America: An Immigrant Economist Explores the Land of Inequality|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=guS3EAAAQBAJ&pg=PA95|location= |publisher=[[Princeton University Press]] |page=95 |isbn=978-0691247625}}</ref></blockquote>
Control over data can lead to different forms of rent-seeking in the digital age, including algorithmic bias and data monopolies. As data monopolies become more prevalent, these firms extract rents from those without access to the valuable information. The consequences of such monopolies can be dire, including decreased innovation and higher consumer costs. Algorithmic bias is an unfortunate reality in the digital landscape, where certain groups can face discrimination based on their race or gender thanks to biased algorithms employed by major platforms.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Botta |first=Federico |author2=Moat, Helen Susannah |title=Digital rentiership and the quantification of value |journal=Theory and Society |volume=49 |issue=4 |year=2020 |pages=529–549}}</ref>
 
Recent studies have examined the relationship between digital platforms, data monopolies and rent seeking. Botta and Moat (2020) believe data-driven business models can create new forms of rentiership by enabling firms to extract value from user-generated data.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Botta |first=Federico |author2=Moat, Helen Susannah |title=Digital rentiership and the quantification of value |journal=Theory and Society |volume=49 |issue=4 |year=2020 |pages=529-549 |doi=10.1007/s11186-020-09409-w}}</ref> Meanwhile, Musiani et al.'s (2021) opinions indicate that Facebook's control of social media data makes it possible for the company to extract rent from third-party app developers through its monopoly power.
 
Rent-seeking can be facilitated through digital platforms, and it's essential to look into this. Firms might utilize dark patterns or algorithms to manipulate consumer behavior and acquire more rent.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Stucke |first1=Maurice E. |last2=Grunes |first2=Allen P. |title=Dark patterns and the GDPR: the role of courts in upholding consumers' privacy |journal=Journal of Antitrust Enforcement |volume=7 |issue=3 |year=2019 |pages=371–406 |issn=2050-0688 |doi=10.1093/jaenfo/jnz018}}</ref>
 
The issue of rent-seeking is common knowledge, yet less attention is given to possible resolutions. It has been proven that transparency and accountability measures can counteract the negative effects of rent-seeking, in addition to anti-corruption laws. One can also utilize competition policy and antitrust laws as solutions to digital platform monopolies and the exploitation of data.
 
In this expanding digital economy, rent-seeking can manifest in novel and diverse ways. Maintaining vigilance of such developments by policymakers and conducting research is imperative to ensure that the digital economy operates justly and fairly.
 
== Possible consequences ==
Line 91 ⟶ 75:
Government agents may initiate rent-seeking, as by soliciting bribes or other favors from the individuals or firms that stand to gain from having special economic privileges, which opens up the possibility of [[Exploitation of labour|exploitation]] of the consumer.<ref name="Dauderstädt">{{cite book |editor=Michael Dauderstädt |editor2=Arne Schildberg |title=Dead Ends of Transition: Rentier Economies and Protectorates |year=2006 |publisher=Campus Verlag |isbn=978-3-593-38154-1 |url-access=registration |url=https://archive.org/details/deadendsoftransi0000unse }}</ref> It has been shown that rent-seeking by [[bureaucracy]] can push up the cost of production of [[Public good (economics)|public good]]s.<ref name=Niskanen>{{cite book |last=Niskanen |first=William |year=1971 |title=Bureaucracy and Representative Government |url=https://archive.org/details/bureaucracyrepre0000nisk |url-access=registration |publisher=Aldine-Atherton, Chicago|isbn=978-0-202-06040-8 }}</ref> It has also been shown that rent-seeking by tax officials may cause loss in revenue to the public exchequer.<ref name="Chowdhury 2006" />
 
[[Mancur Olson|Mançur Olson]] traced the historic consequences of rent seeking in ''The Rise and Decline of Nations''. As a country becomes increasingly dominated by organized interest groups, it loses economic vitality and falls into decline. Olson argued that countries that have a collapse of the political regime and the interest groups that have coalesced around it can radically improve productivity and increase national income because they start with a clean slate in the aftermath of the collapse. An example of this is [[Japanese post-war economic miracle|Japan]] after World War Two. But new coalitions form over time, once again shackling society in order to redistribute wealth and income to themselves. However, social and technological changes have allowed new enterprises and groups to emerge.<ref name=Mokyr>{{Cite journal | url=https://cpb-us-e1.wpmucdn.com/sites.northwestern.edu/dist/3/1222/files/2018/02/Mokyr-Nye-Southern-EconJournal-2k1u4v2.pdf | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191216230454/https://cpb-us-e1.wpmucdn.com/sites.northwestern.edu/dist/3/1222/files/2018/02/Mokyr-Nye-Southern-EconJournal-2k1u4v2.pdf | archive-date=2019-12-16 | title=Distributional Coalitions, the Industrial Revolution, and the Origins of Economic Growth in Britain| journal=Southern Economic Journal| volume=74| issue=1| pages=50–70| year=2007| last1=Mokyr| first1=Joel| last2=Nye| first2=John V. C.| doi=10.1002/j.2325-8012.2007.tb00826.x |id=[https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:sej:ancoec:v:74:1:y:2007:p:50-70 RePEc:sej:ancoec:v:74:1:y:2007:p:50-70]}}</ref>
 
A study by Laband and [[John Sophocleus]] in 1988<ref name=Leeson>{{Cite book |jstor=j.ctt7t3fh|title=The Invisible Hook: The Hidden Economics of Pirates|last1=Leeson|first1=Peter T.|year=2009|isbn=978-0-691-15009-3 |publisher= Princeton University Press|page=191|title-link=The Invisible Hook}}</ref> estimated that rent-seeking had decreased total income in the US by 45 percent. Both Dougan and Tullock affirm the difficulty of finding the cost of rent-seeking. Rent-seekers of government-provided benefits will in turn spend up to that amount of benefit in order to gain those benefits, in the absence of, for example, the collective-action constraints highlighted by Olson. Similarly, taxpayers lobby for loopholes and will spend the value of those loopholes, again, to obtain those loopholes (again absent collective-action constraints). The total of wastes from rent-seeking is then the total amount from the government-provided benefits and instances of tax avoidance (valuing benefits and avoided taxes at zero). Dougan says that the "total rent-seeking costs equal the sum of aggregate current income plus the net deficit of the public sector".<ref name=Dougan>{{cite journal |last=Dougan |first=William R. |year=1991 |title=The Cost of Rent Seeking: Is GNP Negative? |journal=Journal of Political Economy |volume=99 |issue=3 |pages=660–664 |doi=10.1086/261773 |s2cid=154489617 }}</ref>
 
Mark Gradstein writes about rent-seeking in relation to public goods provision, and says that public goods are determined by rent seeking or lobbying activities. But the question is whether private provision with free-riding incentives or public provision with rent-seeking incentives is more inefficient in its allocation.<ref name=Gradstein>{{cite journal |last=Gradstein |first=Mark |year=1993 |title=Rent Seeking and the Provision of Public Goods |journal=The Economic Journal |volume=103 |issue=420 |pages=1236–1243 |doi=10.2307/2234249 |jstor=2234249 }}</ref>
 
Political rent-seeking can also affect immigration. Welfare states incentivise unproductive migration and can create continuation of past behaviour of not accumulating personal wealth and being dependent on government transfers.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Nannestad |first1=Peter |title=Taxing the rich or the poor?: Immigrants on the dole as the socially optimal policy outcome for rational egalitarians |url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/242395368 |website=researchgate |publisher=Res |access-date=3 May 2022}}</ref> Alternatively, productive migrants are incentivised to leave rent-seeking societies, possibly resulting in further economic decline.<ref>{{cite webbook |last1=Hillman |first1=Ayre |title=The Elgar Companion to Public Choice, Second Edition |chapter=Rent Seeking |date=2013 |pages=307–330 |chapter-url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/286953357 |websitedoi=researchgate10.4337/9781849802857.00032 |access-dateisbn=3 May9781849806039 2022}}</ref>
 
The Nobel Memorial Prize-winning economist [[Joseph Stiglitz]] has argued that rent-seeking contributes significantly to [[income inequality in the United States]] through lobbying for government policies that let the wealthy and powerful get income, not as a reward for creating wealth, but by grabbing a larger share of the wealth that would otherwise have been produced without their effort.<ref name=Stiglitz>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (4 June 2012). ''The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future''. p. 32. Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref><ref name=Lind>{{cite news |last=Lind |first=Michael |title=How rich "moochers" hurt America |newspaper=Salon |date=22 March 2013 |url=http://www.salon.com/2013/03/22/how_rich_moochers_ruin_america/ |access-date=7 April 2013}}</ref> [[Thomas Piketty]], [[Emmanuel Saez]], and [[Stefanie Stantcheva]] have analyzed international economies and their changes in tax rates to conclude that much of income inequality is a result of rent-seeking among wealthy tax payers.<ref name=Piketty>{{cite journal |last1=Piketty |first1=Thomas |first2=Emmanuel |last2=Saez |first3=Stefanie |last3=Stantcheva |title=Optimal Taxation of Top Labor Incomes: A Tale of Three Elasticities |journal=American Economic Journal: Economic Policy |volume=6 |issue=1 |year=2014 |pages=230–71 |doi=10.1257/pol.6.1.230 |s2cid=13028796 |url=http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~saez/piketty-saez-stantchevaNBER11thirdelasticity.pdf }}</ref>
 
Laband and [[John Sophocleus]] suggest that the lack of empirical evidence on rent-seeking is due to the broad scope of rent-seeking and rent avoidance activities. Additionally, they suggest that many economic performance measures, such as Gross Domestic Product, include goods and services that are part of the rent-seeking process.<ref>{{cite webjournal |last1=Laband |first1=David |last2=Sophocleus |first2=John |title=Measuring rent-seeking |journal=Public Choice |date=2019 |volume=181 |issue=1–2 |pages=49–69 |url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/325879949 |websitedoi=researchgate10.1007/s11127-018-0566-9 |access-dates2cid=3 May254934890 2022}}</ref>
 
== Possible solutions ==
Rent-seeking has been a complex problem all around the world for a very long time, plaguing many economies.<ref name="Tollison1993">{{cite book |last=Tollison |first=Robert D. |title=Rent Seeking |publisher=Springer |year=1993 |isbn=978-0-89838-241-9}}</ref> It is very unlikely that we will ever see rent-seeking behavior completely eliminated around the world, but there are some potential solutions to mitigate its harmful effects.
 
=== Increased transparency and accountability in government and corporate operations ===
Rent-seeking mainly stems from under the radar operations, aided by the lack of transparency and accountability that involved parties face. Should measures be taken increase transparency and accountability in government and corporate operations, it is likely many parties would be deterred from engaging in rent-seeking behavior.<ref name="shleifer2018">{{cite book |last1=Shleifer |first1=Andrei |last2=Vishny |first2=Robert W. |title=The Grabbing Hand: Government Pathologies and Their Cures |publisher=Harvard University Press |year=2018 |isbn=978-0-674-01014-7}}</ref> Measures such as campaign finance reform, stricter lobbying regulations and increased oversight and reporting requirements for corporations could all aid in deterring rent-seeking activities.
 
=== Reduce the barriers to entry in industries that are prone to rent-seeking behavior ===
Established players are able to use their market power in order to limit competition and extract rents. Measures such as deregulation and the removal of unnecessary licensing requirements would limit the power that these major players currently hold.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Peltzman |first=Sam |year=1976 |title=Toward a More General Theory of Regulation |journal=Journal of Law and Economics |volume=19 |issue=2 |pages=211–240}}</ref>
 
=== Implementing a tax on rent-seeking activities ===
This would work similar to the Pigovian tax, a tax on negative externalities, adding additional costs associated with rent-seeking. These additional costs would likely deter certain rent-seeking activities.<ref>{{cite book |last=Konrad |first=Kai A. |year=2009 |title=Strategy and Dynamics in Contests |publisher=Oxford University Press |isbn=978-0-19-954960-3}}</ref>
 
Although these possible solutions may all be effective at limiting some forms of rent-seeking, each have their own challenges and setbacks. There would undoubtedly be pushback should regulatory measures or taxes be implemented, potentially leading to unintended consequences. It is also likely that political and corporate parties will resist these measures, making it near impossible to pass and enforce them.<ref name="anderson1983">{{cite journal |last1=Anderson |first1=James H. |last2=Anderson |first2=Gary M. |title=Rent-Seeking and Market Structure: Comment |journal=Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE) / Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft |volume=139 |issue=3 |year=1983 |pages=528–532 |doi=10.2307/40751618 |jstor=40751618}}</ref>
 
==See also==
{{Portal|economics|business|law}}
{{div col|colwidth=11em}}
* [[Unjust enrichment]]
* [[Cartel]]
* [[Client politics]]
Line 128 ⟶ 97:
* [[Cybersquatting]]
* [[Price elasticity of supply|Elasticity of supply]]
* [[Enshittification]]
* [[Geolibertarianism]]
* [[Georgism]]
* [[He who does not work, neither shall he eat]]
* [[Intellectual property]]
* [[Landed gentry]]
Line 146 ⟶ 117:
* [[Tragedy of the anticommons]]
* [[Unearned income]]
* [[Unjust enrichment]]
* [[Value capture]]
* [[White-collar crime]]
Line 172 ⟶ 144:
[[Category:Public choice theory]]
 
[[de:Politische RenteRentenökonomie#Rent-Seeking]]